Flyer

Health Science Journal

  • ISSN: 1108-7366
  • Journal h-index: 51
  • Journal CiteScore: 10.69
  • Journal Impact Factor: 9.13
  • Average acceptance to publication time (5-7 days)
  • Average article processing time (30-45 days) Less than 5 volumes 30 days
    8 - 9 volumes 40 days
    10 and more volumes 45 days
Awards Nomination 20+ Million Readerbase
Indexed In
  • Genamics JournalSeek
  • China National Knowledge Infrastructure (CNKI)
  • CiteFactor
  • CINAHL Complete
  • Scimago
  • Electronic Journals Library
  • Directory of Research Journal Indexing (DRJI)
  • EMCare
  • OCLC- WorldCat
  • University Grants Commission
  • Geneva Foundation for Medical Education and Research
  • Euro Pub
  • Google Scholar
  • SHERPA ROMEO
  • Secret Search Engine Labs
Share This Page

Research Article - (2021) Volume 15, Issue 4

Estimation and Comparison of Poverty Line in Different States of India by Using Quality Adjusted Life Year (QALY)

Gurprit Grover1 and Radhika Magan2*

1Department of Statistics, Faculty of Mathematical Sciences, University of Delhi, Delhi

2Department of Statistics, Faculty of Mathematical Sciences, University of Delhi, Delhi

*Corresponding Author:
Radhika Magan
Research Scholar, Department of Statistics, Faculty of Mathematical Sciences, University of Delhi, Delhi
Tel: 09958336303
E-mail: wangshilei@tyercan.com, peptide612@gmail.com/lsun@tulane.edu

Received Date: March 23, 2021; Accepted Date: April 05, 2021; Published Date: April 09, 2021

Citation: Grover G, Magan R (2021) Estimation and Comparison of Poverty Line in Different States of India by Using Quality Adjusted Life Year (QALY). Health Sci J. 15 No. 4: 829.

Visit for more related articles at Health Science Journal

Abstract

Objective: Poverty Line gives a snap-short about the nature of poverty. Our objective is to redefine poverty line as a cost of common utility value across a population. Based on this utility value, we estimate Quality Adjusted Life Year (QALY) for different states of India.

Methods: In this paper, we observe trend analysis on poverty ratios across different states in different time periods. We analyse the change in head count ratio from 2004- 05, 2009-10, 2011-12 across different states. Our cases are more concentrated on subdividing the states into two subgroups and then apply the model stated by Martin (2006). This leads to a new revised poverty model which serve as a framework for computation of QALY.

Results: Over the different time periods, the percentage of number of states are 10%, 36.67%, 86.67% of the total states having QALY value closer to 1in the time period 2004-05, 2009-10, 2011-12 respectively.

Conclusion: There is a huge variation in the QALY values in conjunction to the poverty estimates for different states. Few states whose poverty ratios are better over different time period has better QALY values i.e.closer to 1. The other states which are in worse condition having lower poverty ratios, has indeed QALY values close to 0.

Keywords

Poverty ratio; Utilities; Stratification; Survival needs; QALY

Introduction

India is one of the fastest growing economies in the world with a major objective to eradicate poverty from all the regions of the country. Poverty is defined as a condition of living where households (group of individuals) who don’t possess enough money to meet their basic survival needs [1,2-4]. Poverty line gives a snapshot about the nature of poverty in different regions across India [6]. It not only distinguishes between the rich and poor but also reflects the same level of utility over different commodities. In terms of cost of living indices poverty line is defined by enabling inter-personal welfare comparison, when cost of acquiring basic needs varies over time or space [7-9-14]. An information theoretic approach was used to estimate poverty lines which are consistent and based on consumption pattern was also proposed [2,7]. Poverty lines are also considered as deflators for cost of living differences. These deflators categorise the individuals in such a way that their households with a defined standard of living is considered to be non-poor if they lie above the reference line while those below it are deemed to be poor [15].

Eradication of poverty is an important objective which, the government is dealing from past years. Planning Commission is the central agency which provides poverty estimates by constituting groups from time to time in order to revisit the methodological issues related to measurement of poverty. However there are different methods used for measuring poverty such as poverty line, head count ratio, poverty gap, squared poverty gap, Lorenz curve, gini coefficient, 1$ a day poverty line etc.

In the present study, we examine the trend of poverty across different states of India in different time periods. We analyse the change in head count ratio from 2004-05, 2009-10, 2011-12 across different states [16-18]. Our cases are more concentrated on subdividing the states into two subgroups and then apply the model stated by Martin [19]. Then we redefine poverty line as a cost of common utility value across a population. Further based on this utility value, we estimate Quality Adjusted Life Year (QALY) for different states.

Thus, it is for the first time QALY’s have been computed for region specific areas across different time periods for which poverty ratios were available. Though lot of research is done in the area of computation of QALY using methodologies such as VAS (visual analog scale), standard gamble, TTO (time trade off), EQ-5D, SF-6 etc. But, for the first time new revised poverty model has been constructed which serve as a framework for computation of QALY [20-23].

QALY

Few authors defines poverty as an ill health state of a human being which is due to low income, low nutrient value leading to low standard of living [5]. One of the major reasons for occurrence of poverty is due to income inequality which directly affects the health of an individual. When we ponder about health then it directly relates to how much better is our quality of life. An individual can chose his priority of living a quality of life with or without a disease burden [24]. This quality of life is measured by means of a health outcome called QALY (Quality Adjusted Life Year).

In the present scenario, measurement of health is described in a different way [25-27]. The definition has path itself from the amount of life lived, to how far is the satisfaction level achieved for an individual. QALY is an important measurement of health outcome [28]. However their interpretation related to this health outcome is stated as, “Where should we spend whose money, to undertake what programs, to save whose lives and with what probability?”.This question in turn implies on how many lives are saved alongwith the justification of the resources expanded. QALD (Quality Adjusted Life Days) for childbirth and maternity service in India have also been estimated [11].The QALD’s obtained by the new proposed method are compared with the QALD’s obtained by Afriat method. Both are found to be approximately same. These QALDs are estimated for different quintiles which are classified on the basis of usual monthly per capita expenditure.

Thus QALY is a summary measure which incorporates the impact on quantity as well as quality of life. In all the previous study different approaches have been used to estimate QALY but none of the studies have used polynomial fitting approach. Polynomials of different degree are formulated, tested for goodness of fit and then deriving the estimation of QALD.

Poverty lines give a true picture about prevalence of poverty across different subgroups of a population lying in different geographic areas while QALY gives the quantity and quality of life lived by a population who lie below the poverty line. When we summarise different states by using this health outcome, we are in a way giving an opportunity to those subgroups (populations) lying closer to value 1 who needs slight improvement in their health conditions. Thus a small uplift can make those subgroups rise above poverty line with good QALY values. On the other hand individuals whose values lie closer to 0 indicates that their health condition is bad and needs more improvement by means of income and better nutritional value.

Official poverty lines

Methodology for estimation of poverty has been revised from time to time in order to make poverty estimates appear more relevant in the present scenario. In India, poverty estimates are based on the recommendation of the expert group given by Professor Suresh D. Tendulkar and Dr. C Rangarajan [23]. Planning Commission is the central agency which not only estimates the incidence of poverty at national level but also at the state level [12]. However Tendulkar’s approach is based on extrinsic pre-determined poverty line in terms of monthly per capita expenditure (MPCE). The poverty ratio is obtained by counting the number of person’s lying below poverty line from the class of distributions of persons. CSO (Central Statistical Office) provides the estimates of expenditure of commodities at current and constant prices. The ratio between the two prices gives the consumption deflator.

The expert group disaggregated the official poverty line into state specific poverty line which helps to study the changes in inter-state price differentials. The validity of these official poverty lines were done by comparing the actual private consumption expenditure per capita with the poverty line on food, education, health against the normative expenditure on nutritional, educational and health outcomes derived. All India urban poverty line based on mixed reference period for rural as well as urban areas on the state wise basis for the time period 2004-05 [13].

Utility

The term utility has been defined as a measure of preferences which an individual attaches in a particular health state (NICE guidelines). There is a controversy in defining the measurability of utility [8]. Some authors define it as a measure of satisfaction which is subjective in nature [3]. On the other hand it is also defined as an indicator of preferences which is objective in nature. From economics perspectives, utility is defined in terms of poverty ratio as a valuation of health state of an individual which is assumed to be consistent over a period of time. Following the similar approach given by Ravallion [16], poverty lines are defined with respect to N (N=30) mutually exclusive group of states (j=1,2,…,N) such that all the individuals within a given state share the same utility function defined over various commodities with constant price over a particular year [15]. Each household has its own consumption pattern, which maximise the utility so that it uniquely belongs to a particular state.

The utility function serves two purposes in the analysis. Firstly it gives an idea about the preference of an individual in a particular health state. Secondly it reflects the inter-state differences in terms of consumption. The utility consistent poverty line is defined as minimum cost of common utility level at the prices faced by each state. The consumer expenditure function is ej which is defined as ej(pj,u) giving the minimum cost of utility u in jth state along with vector of price pj. Let uz denote the minimum utility level required to escape poverty by which consistency requires to be constant for all j.

Consumption is used as an indicator for measurement of poverty when income is difficult to measure. It also indicates the differences occurring in the consumption bundles which directly affect the differences in consumption usage to reach the same utility level in different regions. The theory of revealed preferences states that the poverty line for each subgroup in a population is expressed in terms of “welfare”[12]. Economists have further agreed on utility consistency as a functioning based approach [16]. It is also viewed as an alternative theoretic foundation for measurement of poverty [22].

In India, expert group states that a constant method of computing poverty line is done by using each comparison year as a base year. Thus yearly, NSS provides a relationship of per capita expenditure and calorie intake which is different from that of fixing the commodity bundle on the basis of price, income and preferences prevalent in a particular year for deriving the utility function. Most of the past literature relates to the economics theory which is based on the concept of welfare. This in turn supports the poverty line by means of utility function defined on the basis of consumption. Poverty line has also been stated from the point of consumption expenditure function with respect to utility [4].

The minimum income question in terms of consumer expenditure function overcomes the problem of computing utility from demand behaviour in case of alternatives which vary from one household to another. Utility in reference to poverty is defined as one welfare relevant functioning method which refers to attainment of personal satisfaction [18]. Next comes into picture is the reference problem i.e by what means is the reference level of utility (or other functionings) which governs the poverty line. Let person’s functioning (consumption pattern) is determined by the consumption of goods or commodities an individual consumes over a period of time. Consider a particular state i with characteristic xi representing the head count ratio. The utility function is defined as u(qi,xi) where qi is the quantity vector maximising on utility with price vector pi. The total expenditure on consumption is defined as: e(pi, xi, u). Next we define the estimation of QALY.

Thus quality of life can be quantified by using the concept of utility [25]. The utilitarian philosophers describe utility as a measure for increasing or decreasing the value for happiness. People desire for things or goods which in turn leads to maximization of positive utility (pleasure) or negative utility (pain). QALY’s are defined as the summation of utility adjusted values over various time intervals. There lies an underlying assumption for QALY to be of additive separability. It also states that the utility of a given health state is unaffected by the other health state which precedes or follow it.

Methodology

Data has been collected from NSS 61st round (2004-05), NSS 66th round (2009-10), NSS 68th round (2011-12) along with the report of Planning Commission of India [26]. This is a secondary data which enlists the poverty estimates, head count ratio (%), number of people below poverty line (lakhs), share in consumption expenditure of food and non-food items (%), constant prices for health and education for the time period 2004-2012. There is a huge literature related to measurement of poverty along with the study of trend pattern but for the first time it has been done by means of QALY for different states across different time periods.

The major objective of building a model and hereby compute QALY is to uplift those sections of the populations which are lying below poverty line by indexing them on a scale of 0-1. In a way we refer to those particular regions which need more or less improvement through standard of living. Although poverty ratio gives crude idea about the actual condition of different states but QALY gives an exact picture of particular state will lie with respect to a quality of life. To formalise this approach for model building, we assume that there are N mutually exclusive group of states indexed from j =1 to N (N=30). All the individuals within a given state enjoy the same utility function defined over commodities with respect to constant price over a period of time.

Martin model is given by: e(pi, xi, u).

Where e represents the expenditure function, pi refers to per capita per month public expenditure at constant prices (education & health), xi refers to the head count ratio (% of people below poverty line), u represents % share in consumer expenditure for food as well as non-food items.

Test for Heteroscedasticity

Breusch Pagan test is used to test for heteroscedasticity. It tests for error variances in the regression model.

Hypothesis: H0: Error variances are equal

                   H1: Error variances are not equal

The test statistic follows a chi square distribution wherein we accept H0 if p value is greater than 0.05 and reject H0 otherwise at 5% level of significance.

Stratification

We consider all the different states together and try to establish a causal relationship between poverty estimates (dependent variable) and other explanatory variables like head count ratio, below poverty line, utility(food and non-food items). On taking data as a whole, it did not give good results may be due to huge variation in the values across different states.Thus, the above model did not work well. So we further resort to stratify the data. Stratified random sampling is a method of sampling in which we subdivide the population into smaller groups known as strata. This sampling technique gives better precision. The strata so obtained give a better representation of the entire population under study. Since poverty ratios and value of variances differ across the strata so we consider disproportionate stratification.

From Table 1a-3a gives the poverty estimates for different strata with PRU representing the poverty ratio for urban areas, HCRU gives the head count ratio in percentage which is defined as the proportion of population that lives below the poverty line. BPLU represents the number of people below poverty line in lakhs, IHCRU is the inverse of HCRU which is taken on the basis of negative correlation with the poverty ratio. The expected value is given by estimated PRU which lies within the lower confidence interval limit (LCL) and upper confidence interval limit (UCL).

In stratum A1 we have those states for which number of persons below poverty line value is greater than λ (λ=10). We have a sample of 17 states with fitted polynomial equation as:

image          (1.1)

For all the states lying in stratum A1 the poverty estimates obtained from equation (1.1) are given in table 1a and they lie within the confidence interval for the year (2004-05). The value of R2 is 55.86% of the total variation in poverty estimates for stratum A1is explained by the head count ratio for the people who lie below the poverty line based on monthly per capita expenditure (MPCE).

Breusch Pagan test for heteroskedasticity shows that the p value for stratum A1 is 0.1345 (>0.05). Thus we accept H0 i.e. the variances of the error terms are homoscedastic.

States PRU HCRU BPLU IHCRU Est PRU LCL UCL
Andhra Pradesh 563 23.4 51.3 0.042735 587.3869 561.45 613.32
Bihar 526 43.7 40.9 0.022883 521.5728 444.05 599.09
Chattisgarh 514 28.4 13.4 0.035211 555.9324 528.07 583.80
Gujarat 659 20.1 41.9 0.049751 607.451 578.99 635.91
Haryana 626 22.4 15.8 0.044643 593.6568 567.03 620.28
Jharkhand 531 23.8 15.6 0.042017 584.8525 559.15 610.55
Karnataka 588 25.9 50.8 0.03861 571.4733 546.16 596.79
Kerela 585 18.4 15.7 0.054348 616.7619 585.91 647.62
Madhya Pradesh 532 35.1 61.7 0.02849 522.9859 482.57 563.40
Maharashtra 632 25.6 116.1 0.039063 573.3809 548.13 598.63
Odisha 497 37.6 22.7 0.026596 516.5019 474.55 558.46
Punjab 643 18.7 17.2 0.053476 615.1883 584.92 645.46
Rajasthan 568 29.7 42.8 0.03367 548.2946 517.91 578.68
Tamil Nadu 560 19.7 61.3 0.050761 609.7229 580.86 638.59
Uttar Pradesh 532 34.1 130.3 0.029326 526.6535 487.42 565.88
West Bengal 573 24.4 57.9 0.040984 581.0339 555.62 606.45
Delhi 642 12.9 18.9 0.077519 638.1506 563.44 712.87

Table 1a Poverty estimates for stratum A1 (2004-05).

In stratum B1 we have those states for which number of persons below poverty line value is less than λ (λ=10). We have a sample of 13 states with fitted polynomial equation as:

image          (1.2)

For all the states lying in stratum B1 the poverty estimates obtained from equation (1.2) are given in Table 1b and they lie within the confidence interval for the year (2004-05). The value of R2 is 53.63% of the total variation in poverty estimates for stratum B1is explained by the head count ratio for the people who lie below the poverty line based on monthly per capita expenditure (MPCE).

States PRU HCRU BPLU IHCRU Est PRU LCL UCL
Arunachal Pradesh 618 23.5 0.7 0.042553 645.9204 579.96 711.88
Assam 600 21.8 8.4 0.045872 633.122 557.33 708.91
Goa 671 22.2 1.7 0.045045 636.4975 563.37 709.62
Himachal Pradesh 606 4.6 0.3 0.217391 605.7511 436.36 775.15
Jammu & Kashmir 603 10.4 2.9 0.096154 543.4069 418.43 668.39
Manipur 641 34.5 2.1 0.028986 659.6344 500.45 818.82
Meghalaya 746 24.7 1.2 0.040486 652.6573 590.22 715.10
Mizoram 700 7.9 0.4 0.126582 697.2719 529.09 865.45
Nagaland 783 4.3 0.2 0.232558 783.1645 613.75 952.58
Sikkim 742 25.9 0.2 0.03861 657.7006 594.57 720.83
Tripura 556 22.5 1.3 0.044444 638.879 567.63 710.12
Uttarakhand 602 26.2 6.4 0.038168 658.7191 594.68 722.76
Puducherry 506 9.9 0.7 0.10101 561.2754 446.92 675.63

Table 1b Poverty estimates for stratum B1 (2004-05).

Breusch Pagan test for heteroskedasticity shows that the p value for stratum B1 is 0.573 (>0.05). Thus we accept H0 i.e. the variances of the error terms are homoscedastic.

In stratum A2 we have those states for which number of persons below poverty line value is greater than λ (λ=10). We have a sample of 17 states with fitted polynomial equation as:

image          (2.1)

For all the states lying in stratum A2 the poverty estimates obtained from equation (2.1) are given in Table 2a and they lie within the confidence interval for the year (2009-10). The value of R2 is 60.36% of the total variation in poverty estimates for stratum A2 is explained by the head count ratio for the people who lie below the poverty line based on monthly per capita expenditure (MPCE).

State PRU HCRU BPLU ICHRU Est PRU LCL UCL
Andhra Pradesh 926 17.7 48.7 0.056497 959.5788 898.09 1021.06
Assam 871 26.1 11.2 0.038314 921.5818 835.33 1007.84
Bihar 775 39.4 44.8 0.025381 774.7845 630.19 919.38
Chattisgarh 807 23.8 13.6 0.042017 874.9892 811.49 938.49
Goa 1025 14.4 22.9 0.069444 1009.883 901.79 1117.98
Haryana 975 17.9 44.6 0.055866 951.7137 892.01 1011.42
Himachal Pradesh 888 23 19.6 0.043478 863.5944 800.81 926.38
Karnataka 908 31.1 24 0.032154 882.341 786.86 977.83
Kerela 831 19.6 44.9 0.05102 891.7105 829.67 953.75
Madhya Pradesh 772 12.1 18 0.082645 730.6335 605.78 855.49
Maharashtra 961 22.9 44.9 0.043668 862.5407 799.60 925.48
Manipur 955 18.3 90.9 0.054645 936.1338 878.31 993.96
Punjab 961 25.9 17.7 0.03861 917.6304 833.81 1001.45
Sikkim 1035 18.1 18.4 0.055249 943.8771 885.38 1002.37
Tamil Nadu 801 19.9 33.2 0.050251 883.6404 820.00 947.28
Uttar Pradesh 800 12.8 43.5 0.078125 865.0555 777.75 952.36
West Bengal 831 31.7 137.3 0.031546 852.3112 742.19 962.43

Table 2a Poverty estimates for stratum A2 (2009-10).

Breusch Pagan test for heteroskedasticity shows that the p value for stratum A2 is 0.3989 (>0.05). Thus we accept H0 i.e. the variances of the error terms are homoscedastic.

In stratum B2 we have those states for which number of persons below poverty line value is less than λ (λ=10). We have a sample of 13 states with fitted polynomial equation as:

image          (2.2)

For all the states lying in stratum B2 the poverty estimates obtained from equation (2.2) are given in Table 2b and they lie within the confidence interval for the year (2009-10). The value of R2 is 52.21% of the total variation in poverty estimates for stratum B2 is explained by the head count ratio for the people who lie below the poverty line based on monthly per capita expenditure (MPCE).

State PRU HCRU BPLU IHCRU Est PRU LCL UCL
Arunachal Pradesh 925 24.9 0.8 0.040161 830.674 621.71 1039.64
Gujarat 951 6.9 0.6 0.144928 950.9793 694.62 1207.33
Jammu & Kashmir 845 12.6 0.9 0.079365 906.8062 719.20 1094.42
Jharkhand 831 12.8 4.2 0.078125 902.2798 708.43 1096.13
Meghalaya 990 46.4 3.7 0.021552 990.0005 672.00 1308.00
Mizoram 939 24.1 1.4 0.041494 959.739 645.60 1273.88
Nagaland 1148 11.5 0.6 0.086957 940.1899 772.74 1107.64
Orissa 736 25 1.4 0.04 812.4393 570.85 1054.03
Rajasthan 846 1.6 0.1 0.625 828.1596 592.33 1063.99
Tripura 783 5 0.1 0.2 775.4119 473.45 1077.37
Uttarakhand 899 10 0.9 0.1 990.1192 775.06 1205.17
Delhi 1040 17.7 0.3 0.056497 1026.342 711.77 1340.92
Puducherry 778 1.7 0.01 0.588235 797.8593 577.41 1018.31

Table 2b Poverty estimates for stratum B2 (2009-10).

Breusch Pagan test for heteroskedasticity shows that the p value for stratum B2 is 0.6903 (>0.05). Thus we accept H0 i.e. the variances of the error terms are homoscedastic.

In stratum A3 and using table 3a we have those states for which number of persons below poverty line value is greater than λ (λ=10). We have a sample of 13 states with fitted polynomial equation as:

image          (3.1)

For all the states lying in stratum A3 the poverty estimates obtained from equation (3.1) are given in Table 3b and they lie within the confidence interval for the year (2010-11). The value of R2 is 69.25% of the total variation in poverty estimates for stratum A3 is explained by the head count ratio for the people who lie below the poverty line based on monthly per capita expenditure (MPCE).

State PRU HCRU BPLU IHCRU Est PRU LCL UCL
Andhra Pradesh 1009 5.8 17 0.172414 1033.974 629.18 1438.77
Bihar 923 31.2 37.8 0.032051 921.1146 443.42 1398.81
Chattisgarh 849 24.8 15.2 0.040323 972.2925 712.32 1232.27
Goa 1134 9.8 16.5 0.102041 1170.66 930.45 1410.87
Haryana 1167 10.1 26.9 0.09901 1225.502 989.82 1461.18
Karnataka 1089 24.8 20.2 0.040323 972.2925 712.32 1232.27
Kerela 1987 15.3 37 0.065359 1666.238 1308.27 2024.20
Maharashtra 1126 21 43.1 0.047619 1019.119 622.47 1415.76
Manipur 1170 9.1 47.4 0.10989 1046.944 781.34 1312.55
Punjab 1155 17.3 12.4 0.057803 1486.47 1175.54 1797.40
Sikkim 1226 10.7 18.7 0.093458 1333.365 1090.82 1575.91
Tripura 920 6.5 23.4 0.153846 893.0706 594.79 1191.36
Uttarakhand 1082 26.1 118.8 0.038314 1095.958 735.84 1456.08

Table 3a Poverty estimates for stratum A3 (2011-12).

State PRU HCRU BPLU IHCRU Est PRU LCL UCL
Arunachal Pradesh 1060 20.3 0.7 0.049261 1022.41 842.12 1202.70
Assam 1008 20.5 9.2 0.04878 1027.62 840.58 1214.66
Gujarat 1152 4.1 0.4 0.243902 1193.254 960.39 1426.12
Himachal Pradesh 1064 10.3 9.4 0.097087 1077.966 929.98 1225.95
Jammu & Kashmir 988 4.3 0.3 0.232558 932.855 720.85 1144.86
Jharkhand 974 7.2 2.5 0.138889 1031.92 869.01 1194.82
Madhya Pradesh 897 5 8.5 0.2 933.8742 685.46 1182.29
Meghalaya 1154 32.6 2.8 0.030675 1154.663 891.64 1417.68
Mizoram 1155 9.3 0.6 0.107527 1008.061 871.68 1144.44
Nagaland 1302 6.4 0.4 0.15625 1219.263 994.58 1443.95
Orissa 861 16.5 1 0.060606 984.3127 812.65 1155.97
Rajasthan 1002 9.2 9.8 0.108696 1000.271 862.00 1138.55
Tamil Nadu 937 3.7 0.1 0.27027 931.602 669.10 1194.11
Uttar Pradesh 941 7.4 0.8 0.135135 998.8557 829.13 1168.59
West Bengal 981 10.5 3.4 0.095238 1087.928 933.80 1242.06
Delhi 1134 15.4 0.3 0.064935 1004.587 810.08 1199.09
Puducherry 1309 3.4 0.02 0.294118 1309.557 1046.47 1572.64

Table 3b Poverty estimates for stratum B3 (2011-12).

Breusch Pagan test for heteroskedasticity shows that the p value for stratum A3 is 0.0508 (>0.05). Thus we accept H0 i.e. the variances of the error terms are homoscedastic.

In stratum B3 we have those states for which number of persons below poverty line value is less than λ (λ=10). We have a sample of 17 states with fitted polynomial equation as:

image          (3.2)

For all the states lying in stratum B3 the poverty estimates obtained from equation (3.2) are given in Table 3b and they lie within the confidence interval for the year (2010-11). The value of R2 is 68.16 % of the total variation in poverty estimates for stratum B3 is explained by the head count ratio for the people who lie below the poverty line based on monthly per capita expenditure (MPCE).

Breusch Pagan test for heteroskedasticity shows that the p value for stratum B3 is 0.4739 (>0.05). Thus we accept H0 i.e. the variances of the error terms are homoscedastic.

On fitting the polynomial for six strata for three different years we get the estimated poverty ratio and then using the utility function we computed QALY. From table 4.1, PRU gives the poverty ratio for urban areas, Food and Non-food total column

The utility function is defined as

image          (4.1)

Using the Table 4a we have defined the utility function based on yearly data. The utility values are assumed to be constant for a particular year for all the states. Due to unavailability of data we could not fit the varying utility function over different states. After forming the utility function as given by equation (4.1) we next compute the quality adjusted life values for different strata of states. The QALY values are computed using equation (4.2)

image          (4.2)

The length of life for population of individuals residing in different states is assumed to be 1 year. Since the poverty estimates are defined for a yearly basis so we follow the methodology for computation of QALY in the similar manner (Table 4b).

Year PRU FoodT Non-FoodT
2004-05 579 42.5 57.5
2009-10 860 40.7 59.3
2010-11 1000 38.5 61.5

Table 4a Share in consumer expenditure for all India level.

States QALY
(2004-05)
State QALY (2009-10) State QALY
(2009-10)
Andhra Pradesh 0.28 Andhra Pradesh 0.61 Andhra Pradesh 0.84
Bihar 0.13 Assam 0.39 Bihar 0.75
Chattisgarh 0.22 Bihar 0.22 Chattisgarh 0.79
Gujarat 0.34 Chattisgarh 0.41 Goa 0.96
Haryana 0.30 Goa 0.78 Haryana 1
Jharkhand 0.27 Haryana 0.59 Karnataka 0.79
Karnataka 0.25 Himachal Pradesh 0.42 Kerela 1
Kerela 0.37 Karnataka 0.32 Maharashtra 0.83
Madhya Pradesh 0.17 Kerela 0.51 Manipur 0.85
Maharashtra 0.25 Madhya Pradesh 0.67 Punjab 1
Odisha 0.15 Maharashtra 0.42 Sikkim 1
Punjab 0.37 Manipur 0.57 Tripura 0.73
Rajasthan 0.21 Punjab 0.40 Uttarakhand 0.89
Tamil Nadu 0.35 Sikkim 0.58  
Uttar Pradesh 0.17 Tamil Nadu 0.50
West Bengal 0.27 Uttar Pradesh 0.76
Delhi 0.55 West Bengal 0.30

Table 4b QALY values for strata A.

For strata A the sample size varies from 17 to 21 from 2004-12, though for 2004-05 & 2009-10 it remains the same. There are number of 8 states such as Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Chattisgarh, Haryana, Karnataka, Kerela, Maharashtra, Punjab whose position remains constant in strata A with improved QALY values over a period of three different years. For the time period 2004-05 the QALY values remain less than 0.5 for almost all the states except for Delhi. Since their values lie closer to 0 which indicates a bad possible state of health for people of different states who lie below the poverty line. Thus, in that time period it indicates greater improvement is needed for the states in order to rise above the poverty line. For strata A(2009-10), more than half of the number of states have QALY values greater than 0.5. The time period 2009-10 shows better improvement in comparison to 2004-05. Thus a moderate improvement is needed for those states with QALY value greater than 0.5. On the other hand few states with value closer to 0 (or less than 0.5) need greater improvement in terms of QALY which in turn help them to rise above the poverty line. For strata A (2010-11), there are 4 states such as Haryana, Kerela, Punjab, Sikkim whose QALY values is 1. It implies that these states have a stage of perfect health of individuals and are majorly ready to rise above the poverty line. Almost all the other states of this time period have QALY values closer to 1 which also implies that a slight improvement in terms of QALY values can make a larger section of the population lie above the poverty line (Table 4c).

States QALY
(2004-05)
States QALY
(2009-10)
State QALY
(2011-12)
Arunachal Pradesh 0.31 Arunachal Pradesh 0.37 Arunachal Pradesh 0.56
Assam 0.32 Gujarat 0.51 Assam 0.56
Goa 0.32 Jammu & Kashmir 0.80 Gujarat 0.97
Himachal Pradesh 0.10 Jharkhand 0.79 Himachal Pradesh 0.88
Jammu & Kashmir 0.58 Meghalaya 0.24 Jammu & Kashmir 0.76
Manipur 0.21 Mizoram 0.45 Jharkhand 0.84
Meghalaya 0.30 Nagaland 0.91 Madhya Pradesh 0.76
Mizoram 0.30 Odisha 0.36 Meghalaya 0.4
Nagaland 0.21 Rajasthan 0.44 Mizoram 0.82
Sikkim 0.28 Tripura 0.41 Nagaland 0.99
Tripura 0.32 Uttarakhand 0.53 Odisha 0.67
Uttarakhand 0.28 Delhi 0.65 Rajasthan 0.82
Puducherry 0.63 Puducherry 0.43 Tamil Nadu 0.76
  Uttar Pradesh 0.81
West Bengal 0.89
Delhi 0.73
Puducherry 1

Table 4c QALY values for strata B.

For strata B the sample size varies from 13 to 17 from 2004-12, though for 2004-05 & 2009-10 it remains the same. There are number of 6 states such as Arunachal Pradesh, Jammu & Kashmir, Meghalaya, Mizoram, Nagaland, Puducherry whose position remains constant in strata B with improved QALY values over a period of three different years. For the time period 2004-05 the QALY values remain less than 0.5 for almost all the states except for Jammu & Kashmir, Puducherry. Since their values lie closer to 0 which indicates a bad possible state of health for people of different states who lie below the poverty line. Thus, in that time period it indicates greater improvement is needed for the states in order to rise above the poverty line. For strata B(2009-10), half of the number of states have QALY values greater than 0.5. The time period 2009-10 shows better improvement in comparison to 2004-05. Thus a moderate improvement is needed for those states with QALY value greater than 0.5. On the other hand few states with value closer to 0 (or less than 0.5) needs greater improvement in terms of QALY which in turn help them to rise above the poverty line. For strata B (2010-11), there are 3 states such as Gujarat, Nagaland, Puducherry whose QALY values is 1or very close to 1 (approximately). It implies that these states have a stage of perfect health of individuals and are majorly ready to rise above the poverty line. Almost all the other states of this time period have QALY values closer to 1 (except Meghalaya) which also implies that a slight improvement in terms of QALY values can make a larger section of the population lie above the poverty line. Over a period of three time periods, the number of states are 10%, 36.67% , 86.67% of the total states having QALY value closer to 1in the time period 2004-05, 2009-10, 2011-12 respectively.

Conclusion

Poverty line gives the level of income needed to meet the basic survival needs. Earlier poverty was measured on consumption basis while all other dimensions such as calorie requirements, share of consumption expenditure on food & non-food items etc. which were of not much significance. Economists feel that a minimum standard of living is chosen as a reference cut-off for households in order to meet their basic survival needs [10].

Eradication of poverty is an important objective. Human being needs a certain minimum consumption of food and non-food items to survive [17]. Measurement of poverty help us to evaluate the performance of quality of life lived by an individual in order to meet his survival needs. A group of household in a particular area will have different consumption needs, different prices and geographical areas which lead to formation of different poverty estimates. In India there is a variation of climate from north to south or east to west along with variation in lifestyle, standard of living, prices and consumption needs [27,28]. All these criteria indicate that the same consumption bundle cannot be used throughout for all the states which yield the same level of utility.

Poverty lines represent the same level of utility through time and space [20,21]. This concept helps us to make an assumption about utility being constant in a particular year. This paper demarcates the different states on the basis of number of people below poverty line as well as quality of life lived by those sections of the population. The concept behind QALY serves as a great importance for policy makers to identify the quality of life of different states lived by the group of individuals who are deemed to lie below the poverty line. They help in uplifting those sections of the populations whose QALY value is close to 1. Thus by means of providing adequate facilities we can help them rise above the poverty line based on QALY measurement. There is a huge variation in QALY values across different states of India. It indicates that few states are on the verge of better quality of life with QALY value closer to 1 than other states are in worse condition with value close to 0. This will help the policy makers to initiate new frameworks for people lying below the poverty line so that they meet their survival needs at the earliest.

36703

References

  1. Alkire S, Santos ME (2010) Acute multidimensional poverty: A new index for developing countries. OPHI.
  2. Arndt C, Simler KR (2007) Consistent poverty comparisons and inference. Agricultural Economics 37: 133-139.
  3. Arndt C, Simler KR (2010) Estimating utility-consistent poverty lines with applications to Egypt and Mozambique. Economic Development and Cultural Change 58: 449-474
  4. Blackorby C, Donaldson D (1987) Welfare ratios and distributionallysensitive cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Public Economics 34: 265-290.
  5. Chhibber A, Ghosh J, Palanivel, T (2009) The global financial crisis and the Asia-Pacific region. Colombo: UNDP Regional Centre for Asia and the Pacific.
  6. Deaton A (2003) Prices and poverty in India, 1987-200. Economic and political Weekly 38: 362-368.
  7. Deaton A (2008) Price trends in India and their implications for measuring poverty. Economic and Political Weekly 43: 43-49.
  8. Elbers C, Lanjouw JO, Lanjouw P (2003) Micro–level estimation of poverty and inequality. Econometrica 71: 355-364.
  9. Goedhart T, Halberstadt V, Kapteyn A, Van PraagB (1977) The poverty line: concept and measurement,” Journal of Human Resources 12: 503-520.
  10. Gleeve P, Kakwani N (1980) Poverty Analysis for national policy use. United Nations.
  11. Grover G, Das NR, Magan R (2019) On the estimation of QALD (Quality Adjusted Life Days) based on expenditure data for Childbirth and Maternity services in India using utility theory. Indian journal of economic and development 7: 1-9.
  12. Hands DW (2014) Paul Samuelson and revealed preference theory. History of Political Economy 46: 85-116.
  13. Himanshu R, Sen A (2010) Towards new poverty lines for India. Economic & Political Weekly 45: 2-8.
  14. Ravallion M (1998) Poverty lines in theory and practice. The World Bank.
  15. Ravallion M, Lokshin M (2006) Testing poverty lines. Review of Income and Wealth 52: 399-421.
  16. Roberts M, Hsiao W, Berman P, Reich M (2003) Getting health reform right: a guide to improving performance and equity. Oxford university press.
  17. Mathiassen A (2009) A model based approach for predicting annual poverty rates without expenditure data. The Journal of Economic Inequality 7: 117-135.
  18. Sala-i-Martin X (2006) The world distribution of income: falling poverty and… convergence, period. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121: 351-397.
  19. Sen A, Himanshu (2004) Poverty and inequality in India: I. Economic and Political Weekly 39: 4247-4263.
  20. Sen A, Himanshu (2004) Poverty and inequality in India: II. Economic and Political Weekly 39: 4361-4375.
  21. Sen P (2005) Of calories and things: reflections on nutritional norms, poverty lines and consumption behaviour in India. Economic and Political Weekly 40: 4611-4618.
  22. Tendulkar SD, Jain LR (1990) Role of growth and distribution in the observed change in headcount ratio measure of poverty: a decomposition exercise for India. Indian Economic Review 25: 165-205.
  23. Kapteyn A (1994) The measurement of household cost functions. Journal of Population Economics 7: 333-350.
  24. Drummond MF, Sculpher MJ, Claxton K, Stoddart GL, Torrance GW (2015) Methods for the economic evaluation of health care programmes. Oxford University Press.
  25. Planning Commission (2009) Report of the expert group to review the methodology for estimation of poverty. New Delhi: Government of India.
  26. Waheeda ST (2015) Status of poverty in India: state-wise analysis. International journal of Advance research and innovative ideas in education.
  27. Zeckhauser R, Shepard D (1976) Where now for saving lives. Law  Contemp Probs 40: 5-45.